September 4, 2003
Q. What
is the EU's position on the draft modalities paper tabled by the
WTO?
A. We are
supportive of Chairman Perez del Castillo's process and
appreciate the work he has done. There has been progress in some
areas. However, the “Perez de Castillo Draft” is flawed,
although not so fundamentally flawed that it cannot be repaired
in Cancún. We need burden sharing amongst participants. This is
what we do not see so far. As the draft stands, it is only the
developed countries who have to pay - all the others just cash
in.
Some
examples:
·
On domestic support: we are prepared to make huge efforts in
this negotiation, but it is excluded that we commit ourselves to
further reductions beyond the implementation period of this
agreement.
·
On export competition: the draft is weak on state trading
enterprises. These and all other forms of export subsidisation
need to be disciplined in an equivalent manner to the
disciplines proposed for our type of export subsidies. We have
to see a level playing field.
·
On Market Access: the proposal effectively concentrates all
market opening efforts in the developed countries. Major net
food exporters will be able to maintain high tariffs, while
gaining hugely improved access to developed importing countries
This is neither justified nor is it in the interests of the
developing countries themselves. What is the logic of this
proposal?
The
reference to non-trade concerns is far too weak.
Q. What
is the EU/US framework proposal about?
The US and
EU were asked to work together and try and unblock the logjam
the negotiations had reached in July. In response the two
partners worked very hard, and made major efforts to find a
convergence of views. In reaching agreement on a common proposal
the two partners showed their commitment to the success of this
round and their determination to close some of the gaps that had
stalled the negotiating process on agriculture. Further gaps and
obstacles remain; it is now up to other WTO members to assume
their responsibilities too by engaging in the negotiations in a
flexible and constructive manner.
In short:
the US/EU framework proposal deals with the « three pillars » of
domestic support, market access and export competition, while
making it clear that a number of other elements remain to be
addressed. For each of the three pillars the paper provides an
outline of how to carry the negotiations forward, while leaving
the details, and in particular the extent of the future
commitments, to be negotiated.
For
domestic support, the paper provides a framework to
substantially reduce the most trade distorting support (amber
box and de minimis) and it creates a box for less trade
distorting support (previously blue box) which is subject to a
cap.
It
recognises that those who subsidise more will have to reduce
more, but ensuring that all make efforts.
For
market access, there is a formula which takes on board both
the formulas discussed to date (Uruguay Round and so-called
“Swiss” formula), while fully preserving the elements of
flexibility and recognition of the existence of sensitive
products, which is an element of great importance to developing
countries.
In fact,
recognising their importance to developing countries,
flexibility and the recognition of the concept of sensitive
products for reasons of development and food security are
essential points in this paper. Furthermore, a special safeguard
is envisaged for developing countries to protect import
sensitive products. The paper also provides for lower tariff
cuts and longer implementation periods for these countries. In
addition, the importance of existing and future preferential
access for developing countries is recognised. Finally, there is
a commitment from developed countries to seek to provide duty
free access for a certain percentage of their imports from
developing countries.
On export
competition, the framework paper provides several elements.
Firstly a clearly defined parallelism between the disciplines
imposed on export subsidies and exports credits. Secondly, it
provides partial elimination of export subsidisation for a
common list of products of interest for the developing
countries. Thirdly, it provides a path for parallel reduction of
export subsidisation for the products for which subsidies are
not eliminated. In addition to that, there will be clear
discipline on food aid programs to prevent misuse and
disciplines also on the transactions of state trading
enterprises.
Finally, the
paper notes a number of elements of interest but not agreed,
including non-trade concerns, the peace clause and GIs.
Q. Do the
June reforms strengthen the EU's hand in the WTO?
A. Yes, they
do. Thanks to the June decision on reform, we can support our
political arguments with clear evidence that we are continuing
to practise what we preach, with a policy that meets society's
broader needs, while significantly cutting back on trade
distorting support and keeping our market open to trade with
third countries. In fact, the reform greatly facilitated the
work to find convergence with the US in the framework proposal,
particularly on domestic support. In this sense it has already
shown its value in terms of a positive contribution to the
negotiations.
Q. What
is decoupling and what will it achieve in WTO terms?
A.
Decoupling means cutting the link between production and
subsidies, and support given in this way does not distort trade.
The move to single farm payments strengthens the position of the
EU since decoupling changes the significance for the WTO of
direct payments. They will no longer be classified as blue box,
but as green box. This latter (green) box includes those forms
of domestic support which are not, or are only minimally,
trade-distorting.
Q. What
is in it for developing countries?
A. The June
2003 CAP reforms will improve the long-term coherence between
the CAP and the Doha Development Agenda. The main adjustments
are expected to reduce the potential for EU surpluses to weigh
on world markets, by reorienting the CAP towards less
trade-distorting domestic support and more extensive
agricultural practices.
Q. How
does the EU justify CAP expenditure that amounts effectively to
$2/day per cow?
A. This
argument is irrelevant. It distracts attention from the key
issue at stake: the question is not how much a country supports
its farming community, but rather what part of that support is
trade-distorting. This is what matters for developing countries.
The June 2003 CAP reforms clearly move the bulk of agricultural
support to non trade-distorting decoupled single farm payments.
Q. The EU
is shifting support to new mechanisms but the same amount of
money goes to farming doesn't it?
A. This
argument is missing the point. What really matters in the
context of the WTO and especially for developing countries is
the impact of farm subsidies on production and trade. Here CAP
reform is clearly positive. Take a look at the recent OECD study
which shows the trade effects of various policy options. It is
clear that thanks to the reform, the bulk of EU subsidisation of
agriculture will move to less or non-trade distorting
mechanisms. This means that they will no longer impact
negatively on world markets.
Unfortunately, some of our trading partners and some NGOs are
deliberately or not blurring the real issue in the WTO talks.
Not all farm spending is evil. This is confirmed by OECD
research, and by the fact that the WTO itself differentiates
between trade distorting (amber box), less trade distorting
(blue box) and non trade distorting (green box) agricultural
support.
The common
objective in the WTO is to reduce farm subsidies, including
those of the EU, which distort international trade and harm the
interests of developing countries. The rest is rhetoric. And it
is this common objective that we are pursuing in our reforms.
Q. Aren't
Geographical Indications just another form of trade barrier,
serving EU interests only?
A. No, GIs
are not trade barriers as they do not concern imports. The EU
simply wants to ensure that its exports are not impeded, either
because they fall foul of trademark rules or because they are
forced to compete on the same markets with non-EU products
bearing similar names but which do not meet the same quality
criteria. It is simply not acceptable that the EU cannot sell
its genuine Italian Parma Ham in Canada because the trade mark
“Parma Ham” is reserved a ham produced in Canada. Caused loss
for Italian Parma producers: € 3.5 million a year.
Q. Is
Europe alone with its bid to step up protection for regional
quality products?
Clearly not.
This is also close to the heart of many developing countries.
India, Pakistan, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Kenya, Jamaica and other
developing countries have demanded better GI protection. They
are worried about multinationals patenting and selling “Basmati”
rice, “Ceylon” tea, “Blue Mountain” coffee, “Jasmine” rice. The
EU proposal would help these countries reap the benefits of the
TRIPs Agreement. Today, 6000 million pounds of “Antigua Coffee”
are produced in such region of Guatemala but 50000 million
pounds are sold under that name around the world. Similarly,
10.000 million kg of “Darjeeling” tea are produced in India, but
30.000 million are sold under the same name around the world.
Q. How do
export credits distort trade?
A. It is not
widely recognised, but is nevertheless true that EU export
refunds are by far not the only trade distorting tools to boost
exports. Some WTO Members resort to state supported export
credits for a significant part of their trade in order to
capture market share in developing countries. According to an
OECD study, the US used about US $ 4 billion of officially
supported export credits in 1998. These practices, which are
highly trade-distorting, should be disciplined in the same way
as other forms of export subsidy. The OECD identified US
payments and long-term credits as the source of 97 % of the
world's trade-distorting export credit subsidies. US credit
subsidies are made on commodities which are already cheap, owing
to the effects of counter-cyclical subsidies, giving
considerable additional leverage to this instrument.
Q. And
single desk selling (state trading enterprises)?
A. State
trading enterprises (and other forms of single desk seller) that
have been granted special rights or privileges by their
Government should also be disciplined. Their practices, such as
cross-subsidisation and price pooling, which are not in
accordance with commercial practices, and which therefore
distort export trade, should be addressed in the WTO
negotiations.
Q. How
have food aid systems been used to distort trade and how can
they harm developing countries?
A.
Irresponsible deployment of commodities under the cover of food
aid programmes is an abuse of the concept. Dangers include:
disturbance of local markets; undermining local agriculture;
displacement of legitimate importers; and circumvention of WTO
rules on subsidised exports. The EU does not at all question the
granting of genuine food aid. We question the use of food aid
donations used as surplus disposal measures. Some WTO members
have used food aid donations more as a production and commercial
tool to dispose of surpluses and promote sales in foreign
markets than as a development tool tailored to the needs of the
recipient countries. It is ironic that the amount of food aid
given by some countries tends to increase significantly when
prices are low whereas levels are much lower when prices are
high - and food aid is most needed.
Q. Why
does the EU want clarification of the 'Precautionary Principle'?
A. In the
interests of food safety we believe that the EU, like other WTO
members, has the right to establish the level of protection that
it deems appropriate. The precautionary principle covers cases
where scientific evidence is insufficient, inconclusive or
uncertain and preliminary scientific evaluation indicates that
there are reasonable grounds for concern about potentially
dangerous effects on the environment, human, animal or plant
health. In order to avoid trade abuses the EU believes that
there is a clear need for clarification of the use of the
precautionary principle.
Q. Does
the CAP not harm poorer countries, for example via the 'dumping'
of subsidised food products on third country markets?
A.
Descriptions of the 'harm' done by the CAP to third countries
tend to exaggerate, when they are not totally incorrect. The EU
has reacted when there have been negative impacts resulting from
its exports, as was the case of beef to West Africa in the
1980s, when the EU stopped granting export subsidies. However,
experience shows that the simple withdrawal from the EU does not
automatically help developing countries, given that the market
space created by such withdrawal is frequently taken over by
products from other developed countries which are equally
competitive.
In addition,
the CAP reforms of the last decade have greatly minimized the
risk of harming developing countries: the proportion of the CAP
budget spent on refunds is down from 30% of the EU farm budget
in 1993 to less than 9% in 2002. And the EU is ready to do more.
Following the June 2003 reform package, the EU will be in a
position to further reduce export subsidies. In the WTO talks,
the EU has offered to completely eliminate its refunds for
certain products important to developing countries, if other
forms of export subsidisation (export credits, abuse of food
aid, state trading enterprises) are equally disciplined.
Q. Do the
EU's existing trade concessions and proposed new ones have a
real benefit for developing countries? Do they receive a
quantifiable benefit?
A. The
Uruguay Round (URAA) did provide important new opportunities for
developing countries - they accounted for almost half (US $
47bn) of the nearly US $ 100bn growth in agricultural trade
between 1993 and 1998. Their exports increased by 72 % in that
period, from US $ 120bn to US $ 167bn. The EU has been an
important source of this growth. Following the URAA,
agricultural imports from developing countries have had annual
growth rates of 5 % (1996-2001), compared to a previous 3 %
(1990-1995).
Q. Can we
still talk about 'Fortress
Europe'?
A. This is
far from being the case. The EU is the world's largest importer
of agricultural products. In 2000 the EU imported agricultural
products totalling EUR 58.6 billion (60 % of these imports
originated in developing countries). The EU imports more farm
products from developing countries than the US, Canada,
Australia and Japan put together.
Q. Tariff
escalation is a big problem for developing countries what does
the EU do to help?
A. Tariff
escalation in agricultural processed products (ie. higher
tariffs for processed products than for the sum of tariffs on
their raw materials) encourages developing countries to export
raw commodities without adding value. It is therefore very
difficult to exploit the dynamics of industrialisation and
development that accompany processing of agricultural
commodities. The EU is not a great user of tariff escalation. In
comparison, Japan and Canada are. For the poorest countries,
tariff escalation in the EU market is not a problem since, given
the Everything But Arms initiative, those countries face no
tariffs on any of their agricultural exports, whether processed
or not.
Q. Why do
EU cotton subsidies not harm developing countries?
A. Although
the EU does subsidise its cotton production, the quantities
which benefit from subsidies are limited.
In fact,
subsidised EU production represents only 2% of world production.
Moreover, the EU is the largest importer of cotton in the world,
and a large share of those imports come from the West and
Central African countries, and pay zero duty. Exports of cotton
from the EU are minimal, and receive no export subsidies.
Against this background it is difficult to sustain that EU
cotton subsidies harm developing countries. |